4214 words

Book Re­view: Red Plenty

Sep­tem­ber 24, 2014

I

I de­cided to read Red Plenty be­cause my biggest gripe after read­ing Singer’s book on Marx was that Marx re­fused to plan how com­mu­nism would ac­tu­ally work, in­stead pre­fer­ring to leave the en­tire mat­ter for the World-​Spirit to sort out. But al­most every­thing that in­ter­ests me about Com­mu­nism falls under the cat­e­gory of “how com­mu­nism would ac­tu­ally work”. Red Plenty, a semi-​fictionalized ac­count of the his­tory of so­cial­ist eco­nomic plan­ning, seemed like a nat­ural follow-​up.

But I’d had it on my List Of Things To Read for even longer than that, ever after stum­bling across a quote from it on some blog or other:

Marx had drawn a night­mare pic­ture of what hap­pened to human life under cap­i­tal­ism, when every­thing was pro­duced only in order to be ex­changed; when true qual­i­ties and uses dropped away, and the human power of mak­ing and doing it­self be­came only an ob­ject to be traded.

Then the mak­ers and the things made turned alike into com­modi­ties, and the mo­tion of so­ci­ety turned into a kind of zom­bie dance, a grim ca­vort­ing whirl in which ob­jects and peo­ple blurred to­gether till the ob­jects were half alive and the peo­ple were half dead. Stock-​market prices acted back upon the world as if they were in­de­pen­dent pow­ers, re­quir­ing fac­to­ries to be opened or closed, real human be­ings to work or rest, hurry or daw­dle; and they, hav­ing given the trans­fu­sion that made the stock prices come alive, felt their flesh go cold and im­per­sonal on them, mere mech­a­nisms for chunk­ing out the man-​hours. Liv­ing money and dying hu­mans, metal as ten­der as skin and skin as hard as metal, tak­ing hands, and danc­ing round, and round, and round, with no way ever of stop­ping; the quick­ened and the dead­ened, whirling on.

And what would be the al­ter­na­tive? The con­sciously arranged al­ter­na­tive? A dance of an­other na­ture. A dance to the music of use, where every step ful­filled some real need, did some tan­gi­ble good, and no mat­ter how fast the dancers spun, they moved eas­ily, be­cause they moved to a human mea­sure, in­tel­li­gi­ble to all, cho­sen by all.

Need­less to say, this is Rel­e­vant To My In­ter­ests, which in­clude among them po­etic al­le­gories for co­or­di­na­tion prob­lems. And I was not dis­ap­pointed.

II

The book be­gins:

Strange as it may seem, the gray, op­pres­sive USSR was founded on a fairy tale. It was built on the twentieth-​century magic called “the planned econ­omy,” which was going to gush forth an abun­dance of good things that the lands of cap­i­tal­ism could never match. And just for a lit­tle while, in the heady years of the late 1950s, the magic seemed to be work­ing. Red Plenty is about that mo­ment in his­tory, and how it came, and how it went away; about the brief era when, under the rash lead­er­ship of Khrushchev, the So­viet Union looked for­ward to a fu­ture of rich com­mu­nists and en­vi­ous cap­i­tal­ists, when Moscow would out-​glitter Man­hat­tan and every Lada would be bet­ter en­gi­neered than a Porsche. It’s about the sci­en­tists who did their gen­uinely bril­liant best to make the dream come true, to give the tyranny its happy end­ing.

And this was the first in­ter­est­ing thing I learned.

There’s a very set­tled mod­ern ex­pla­na­tion of the con­flict be­tween cap­i­tal­ism and com­mu­nism. Cap­i­tal­ism is good at grow­ing the econ­omy and mak­ing coun­tries rich. Com­mu­nism is good at car­ing for the poor and pro­mot­ing equal­ity. So your choice be­tween cap­i­tal­ism and com­mu­nism is a trade-​off be­tween those two things.

But for at least the first fifty years of the Cold War, the So­vi­ets would not have come close to grant­ing you that these are the premises on which the bat­tle must be fought. They were of­fi­cially quite cer­tain that any day now Com­mu­nism was going to prove it­self bet­ter at eco­nomic growth, bet­ter at mak­ing peo­ple rich quickly, than cap­i­tal­ism. Even un­of­fi­cially, most of their lead­ers and econ­o­mists were pretty cer­tain of it. And for a lit­tle while, even their cap­i­tal­ist en­e­mies se­cretly wor­ried they were right.

The ar­gu­ments are easy to un­der­stand. Under cap­i­tal­ism, plu­to­crats use the prof­its of in­dus­try to buy giant yachts for them­selves. Under com­mu­nism, the prof­its can be rein­vested back into the in­dus­try to build more fac­to­ries or to make pro­duc­tion more ef­fi­cient, in­creas­ing growth rate.

Under cap­i­tal­ism, every­one is com­pet­ing with each other, and much of your bud­get is spent on zero-​sum games like ad­ver­tis­ing and mar­ket­ing and sales to give you a leg up over your com­pe­ti­tion. Under com­mu­nism, there is no need to play these zero-​sum games and that part of the bud­get can be rein­vested to grow the in­dus­try more quickly.

Under cap­i­tal­ism, every­one is work­ing against every­one else. If Ford dis­cov­ers a clever new car-​manufacturing tech­nique, their first im­pulse is to patent it so GM can’t use it, and GM’s first im­pulse is to hire thou­sands of lawyers to try to thwart that at­tempt. Under com­mu­nism, every­one is work­ing to­gether, so if one car-​manufacturing col­lec­tive dis­cov­ers a new tech­nique they send their blue­prints to all the other car-​manufacturing col­lec­tives in order to help them out. So in cap­i­tal­ism, each com­pa­nies will pos­sess a few in­di­vid­ual ad­vances, but under com­mu­nism every col­lec­tive will have every ad­vance, and so be more pro­duc­tive.

These ar­gu­ments make a lot of sense to me, and they def­i­nitely made sense to the Com­mu­nists of the first half of the 20th cen­tury. As a re­sult, they were con­fi­dent of over­tak­ing cap­i­tal­ism. They re­al­ized that they’d started with a hand­i­cap – czarist Rus­sia had been dirt poor and al­most with­out an in­dus­trial base – and that they’d faced a fur­ther hand­i­cap in hav­ing the Nazis burn half their coun­try dur­ing World War II – but they fig­ured as soon as they over­came these hand­i­caps their nat­ural ad­van­tages would let them leap ahead of the West in only a cou­ple of decades. The great Russ­ian ad­vances of the 50s – Sput­nik, Gagarin, etc – were seen as ev­i­dence that this was al­ready start­ing to come true in cer­tain fields.

And then it all went wrong.

III

Grant that com­mu­nism re­ally does have the above ad­van­tages over cap­i­tal­ism. What ad­van­tage does cap­i­tal­ism have?

The clas­sic an­swer is that dur­ing com­mu­nism no one wants to work hard. They do as lit­tle as they can get away with, then slack off be­cause they don’t reap the re­wards of their own labor. Red Plenty doesn’t re­ally have the­ses. In fact, it’s not re­ally a non-​fiction work at all. It’s a dra­ma­tized se­ries of episodes in the lives of Russ­ian work­ers, politi­cians, and aca­d­e­mics, in­tended to come to­gether to paint a pic­ture of how the So­viet econ­omy worked.

But if I can im­pose a the­sis upon the text, I don’t think it agreed with this. In cer­tain cases, Rus­sians were very well-​incentivized by things like “We will kill you un­less you meet the pro­duc­tion tar­get”. Later, when the state be­came less murder-​happy, the threat of death faded to threats of de­mo­tions, ru­ined ca­reers, and trans­fer to back­wa­ter provinces. And there were equal in­cen­tives, in the form of pro­mo­tion or trans­fer to a de­sir­able lo­ca­tion such as Moscow, for over­per­for­mance. There were even mon­e­tary bonuses, al­though money bought a lot less than it did in cap­i­tal­ist coun­tries and was uni­ver­sally con­sid­ered in­fe­rior to sta­tus in terms of pur­chas­ing power. Yes, there were Good­hart’s Law type is­sues going on – if you’re being judged per prod­uct, bet­ter pro­duce ten mil­lion de­fec­tive prod­ucts than 9,999,999 ex­cel­lent prod­ucts – but that wasn’t the crux of the prob­lem. Red Plenty pre­sented the prob­lem with the So­viet econ­omy pri­mar­ily as one of al­lo­ca­tion. You could have a per­fectly good fac­tory that could be pro­duc­ing lots of use­ful things if only you had one extra eensy-​weensy part, but un­less the higher-​ups had al­lo­cated you that part, you were out of luck. If that part hap­pened to break, get­ting a new one would de­pend on how much clout you (and your su­pe­ri­ors) pulled ver­sus how much clout other peo­ple who wanted parts (and their su­pe­ri­ors) held.

The book il­lus­trated this re­al­ity with a se­ries of sto­ries (I’m not sure how many of these were true, ver­sus use­ful drama­ti­za­tions). In one, a pig farmer in Siberia needed wood in order to build sties for his pigs so they wouldn’t freeze – if they froze, he would fail to meet his pro­duc­tion tar­get and his ca­reer would be ru­ined. The gov­ern­ment, which mostly dealt with pig farm­ing in more tem­per­ate areas, hadn’t ac­counted for this and so hadn’t al­lo­cated him any wood, and he didn’t have enough clout with of­fi­cials to re­quest some. A fac­tory nearby had extra wood they weren’t using and were going to burn be­cause it was too much trou­ble to fig­ure out how to get it back to the gov­ern­ment for re-​allocation. The farmer bought the wood from the fac­tory in an under-​the-table deal. He was caught, which usu­ally wouldn’t have been a prob­lem be­cause every­body did this sort of thing and it was kind of the “smok­ing mar­i­juana while white” of So­viet of­fenses. But at that par­tic­u­lar mo­ment the Party higher-​ups in the area wanted to make an ex­am­ple of some­one in order to look like they were on top of their game to their higher-​ups. The pig farmer was sen­tenced to years of hard labor.

A tire fac­tory had been as­signed a tire-​making ma­chine that could make 100,000 tires a year, but the gov­ern­ment had got­ten con­fused and as­signed them a pro­duc­tion quota of 150,000 tires a year. The fac­tory lead­ers were stuck, be­cause if they tried to cor­rect the gov­ern­ment they would look like they were chal­leng­ing their su­pe­ri­ors and get in trou­ble, but if they failed to meet the im­pos­si­ble quota, they would all get de­moted and their ca­reers would come to an end. They learned that the tire-​making-machine-making com­pany had re­cently in­vented a new model that re­ally could make 150,000 tires a year. In the spirit of Chen Sheng, they de­cided that since the penalty for miss­ing their quota was some­thing ter­ri­ble and the penalty for sab­o­tage was also some­thing ter­ri­ble, they might as well take their chances and de­stroy their own ma­chin­ery in the hopes the gov­ern­ment sent them the new im­proved ma­chine as a re­place­ment. To their de­light, the gov­ern­ment be­lieved their story about an “ac­ci­dent” and al­lot­ted them a new tire-​making ma­chine. How­ever, the tire-​making-machine-making com­pany had de­cided to can­cel pro­duc­tion of their new model. You see, the new model, al­though more pow­er­ful, weighed less than the old ma­chine, and the gov­ern­ment was mea­sur­ing their pro­duc­tion by kilo­gram of ma­chine. So it was eas­ier for them to just con­tinue mak­ing the old less pow­er­ful ma­chine. The tire fac­tory was al­lo­cated an­other ma­chine that could only make 100,000 tires a year and was back in the same quandary they’d started with.

It’s easy to see how all of these prob­lems could have been solved (or would never have come up) in a cap­i­tal­ist econ­omy, with its use of prices set by sup­ply and de­mand as an al­lo­ca­tion mech­a­nism. And it’s easy to see how thor­oughly the So­viet econ­omy was sab­o­tag­ing it­self by avoid­ing such prices.

IV

The “hero” of Red Plenty – al­though most of the vi­gnettes didn’t in­volve him di­rectly – was Leonid Kan­torovich, a So­viet math­e­mati­cian who thought he could solve the prob­lem. He in­vented the tech­nique of lin­ear pro­gram­ming, a method of solv­ing op­ti­miza­tion prob­lems per­fectly suited to al­lo­cat­ing re­sources through­out an econ­omy. He im­me­di­ately re­al­ized its po­ten­tial and wrote a nice let­ter to Stalin po­litely sug­gest­ing his cur­rent method of doing eco­nom­ics was wrong and he could do bet­ter – this dur­ing a time when every­one else in Rus­sia was des­per­ately try­ing to avoid hav­ing Stalin no­tice them be­cause he tended to kill any­one he no­ticed. Luck­ily the let­ter was in­ter­cepted by a kindly mid-​level of­fi­cial, who kept it away from Stalin and ware­housed Kan­torovich in a uni­ver­sity some­where.

Dur­ing the “Khr­uschev thaw”, Kan­torovich started get­ting some more po­lit­i­cally adept fol­low­ers, the higher-​ups started tak­ing note, and there was a real move­ment to get his ideas im­ple­mented. A few in­dus­tries were run on Kan­torovichian prin­ci­ples as a test case and seemed to do pretty well. There was an in­evitable back­lash. Op­po­nents ac­cused the lin­ear pro­gram­mers of being capitalists-​in-disguise, which wasn’t helped by their use of some­thing called “shadow prices”. But the com­bi­na­tion of their own po­lit­i­cal adept­ness and some high-​level sup­port from Khr­uschev – who alone of all the So­viet lead­ers seemed to re­ally be­lieve in his own cause and be a pretty okay guy – put them within arm’s reach of get­ting their plans im­ple­mented.

But when el­e­ments of lin­ear pro­gram­ming were adopted, they were adopted piece­meal and tooth­less. The book places the blame on Alexei Kosy­gen, who im­ple­mented a bunch of eco­nomic re­forms that failed, in a chap­ter that makes it clear ex­actly how con­strained the So­viet lead­er­ship re­ally was. You hear about Stalin, you imag­ine these guys hav­ing total power, but in re­al­ity they walked a nar­row line, and all these “shadow prices” re­quired more po­lit­i­cal cap­i­tal than they were will­ing to mo­bi­lize, even when they thought Kan­torovich might have a point.

V

In the end, I was left with two con­tra­dic­tory im­pres­sions from the book.

First, amaze­ment that the So­viet econ­omy got as far as it did, given how in­cred­i­bly screwed up it was. You hear about how many stu­pid things were going on at every level, and you think: This was the coun­try that built Sput­nik and Mir? This was the coun­try that al­most buried us be­neath the tide of his­tory? It is a credit to the Russ­ian peo­ple that they were able to build so much as a screw­driver in such con­di­tions, let alone a space sta­tion.

But sec­ond, a sense of what could have been. What if Stalin hadn’t mur­dered most of the com­pe­tent peo­ple? What if en­tire fields of sci­ence hadn’t been banned for silly rea­sons? What if Kan­torovich had been able to make the So­viet lead­er­ship base its eco­nomic plan­ning around lin­ear pro­gram­ming? How might his­tory have turned out dif­fer­ently?

One of the book’s most frequently-​hammered-in points was that there was was a brief mo­ment, back dur­ing the 1950s, when every­thing seemed to be going right for Rus­sia. Its year-​on-year GDP growth (as es­ti­mated by im­par­tial out­side ob­servers) was some­where be­tween 7 to 10%. Star­va­tion was going down. Lux­u­ries were going up. Kan­torovich was fix­ing en­tire in­dus­tries with his lin­ear pro­gram­ming meth­ods. Then Khr­uschev made a se­ri­ous of crazy loose can­non de­ci­sions, he was ousted by Brezh­nev, Kan­torovich was pushed aside and ig­nored, the “Khr­uschev thaw” was re­versed and tight­ened up again, and every­thing stag­nated for the next twenty years.

If Khr­uschev had stuck around, if Kan­torovich had suc­ceeded, might the com­mon knowl­edge that Com­mu­nism is ter­ri­ble at pro­duc­ing ma­te­r­ial pros­per­ity look a lit­tle dif­fer­ent?

The book very briefly men­tioned a com­pet­ing the­ory of re­source al­lo­ca­tion pro­moted by Vic­tor Glushkov, a cy­ber­neti­cist in Ukraine. He thought he could use com­put­ers – then a very new tech­nol­ogy – to cal­cu­late op­ti­mal al­lo­ca­tion for every­one. He failed to nav­i­gate the po­lit­i­cal seas as adroitly as Kan­torovich’s fac­tion, and the killing blow was a paper that pointed out that for him to do every­thing re­ally cor­rectly would take a hun­dred mil­lion years of com­put­ing time.

That was in 1960. If com­put­ing power dou­bles every two years, we’ve un­der­gone about 25 dou­bling times since then, sug­gest­ing that we ought to be able to per­form Glushkov’s cal­cu­la­tions in three years – or three days, if we give him a lab of three hun­dred sixty five com­put­ers to work with. There could have been this en­tire field of cen­tral­ized eco­nomic plan­ning. Maybe it would have con­tin­ued to un­der­per­form prices. Or maybe after decades of trial and error across the en­tire So­viet Union, it could have caught up. We’ll never know. Glushkov and Kan­torovich were mar­gin­al­ized and left to play around with toy prob­lems until their deaths in the 80s, and as far as I know their ideas were never de­vel­oped fur­ther in the con­text of a na­tional planned econ­omy.

VI

One of the ways peo­ple like in­sult­ing smart peo­ple, or ra­tio­nal peo­ple, or sci­en­tists, is by telling them they’re the type of peo­ple who are at­tracted to Com­mu­nism. “Oh, you think you can con­trol and un­der­stand every­thing, just like the Com­mu­nists did.”

And I had al­ways thought this was a pretty awful in­sult. The peo­ple I know who most iden­tify as ra­tio­nal­ists, or sci­en­tif­i­cally/tech­ni­cally minded, are also most likely to be lib­er­tar­ian. So there, case dis­missed, every­body go home.

This book was the first time that I, as a per­son who con­sid­ers him­self ra­tio­nally/tech­ni­cally minded, re­al­ized that I was super at­tracted to Com­mu­nism.

Here were peo­ple who had a clear view of the prob­lems of human civ­i­liza­tion – all the greed, all the waste, all the zero-​sum games. Who had the en­tire pop­u­la­tion united around a vi­sion of a bet­ter fu­ture, whose back­ers could di­rect the en­tire state to bet­ter serve the goal. All they needed was to solve the en­gi­neer­ing chal­lenges, to solve the equa­tions, and there they were, at the golden fu­ture. And they were smart enough to be wor­thy of the prob­lem – Glushkov in­vented cy­ber­net­ics, Kan­torovich won a Nobel Prize in Eco­nom­ics.

And in the end, they never got the chance. There’s an in­ter­pre­ta­tion of Com­mu­nism as a refu­ta­tion of so­cial sci­ence, here were these peo­ple who prob­a­bly knew some so­cial sci­ence, but did it help them run a state, no it didn’t. But from the lit­tle I learned about So­viet his­tory from this book, this seems di­a­met­ri­cally wrong. The So­vi­ets had prac­ti­cally no so­cial sci­ence. They hated so­cial sci­ence. You would think they would at least have some good Marx­ists, but ap­par­ently Stalin killed all of them just in case they might come up with ver­sions of Marx­ism he didn’t like, and in terms of a vi­brant schol­arly field it never re­cov­ered. Eco­nom­ics was tainted with its as­so­ci­a­tion with cap­i­tal­ism from the very be­gin­ning, and when it hap­pened at all it was done by non-​professionals. Kan­torovich was a math­e­mati­cian by train­ing; Glushkov a com­puter sci­en­tist.

So­viet Com­mu­nism isn’t what hap­pens when you let nerds run a coun­try, it’s what hap­pens when you kill all the nerds who are ex­perts in country-​running, bring in nerds from un­re­lated fields to re­place them, then make nice noises at those nerds in prin­ci­ple while com­pletely ig­nor­ing them in prac­tice. Also, you ban all Jews from po­si­tions of im­por­tance, be­cause fuck you.

Baggy two-​piece suits are not the ob­vi­ous cos­tume for philoso­pher kings: but that, in the­ory, was what the ap­pa­ratchiks who rule the So­viet Union in the 1960s were sup­posed to be. Lenin’s state made the same bet that Plato had twenty-​five cen­turies ear­lier, when he pro­posed that en­light­ened in­tel­li­gence gives ab­solute pow­ers would serve the pub­lic good bet­ter than the grubby pol­i­tick­ing of re­publics.

On paper, the USSR was a re­pub­lic, a grand multi-​ethnic fed­er­a­tion of re­publics in­deed and its con­sti­tu­tions (there were sev­eral) guar­an­teed its cit­i­zens all man­ner of civil rights. But in truth the So­viet sys­tem was ut­terly un­sym­pa­thetic to the idea of rights, if you meant by them any sug­ges­tion that the two hun­dred mil­lion men, women and chil­dren who in­hab­ited the So­viet Union should be au­tonomously fix­ing on two hun­dred mil­lion sep­a­rate di­rec­tions in which to pur­sue hap­pi­ness. This was a so­ci­ety with just one pro­gramme for hap­pi­ness, which had been de­clared to be sci­en­tific and there­fore was as fac­tual as grav­ity.

But the So­viet ex­per­i­ment had run into ex­actly the dif­fi­culty that Plato’s ad­mir­ers en­coun­tered, back in the fifth cen­tury BC, when they at­tempted to mould philo­soph­i­cal monar­chies for Syra­cuse and Mace­do­nia. The recipe called for rule by heavily-​armed virtue—or in the Lenin­ist case, not ex­actly virtue, but a sort of in­ten­tion­ally post-​ethical coun­ter­part to it, self-​righteously bru­tal. Wis­dom was to be set where it could be ruth­less. Once such a sys­tem ex­isted, though, the qual­i­ties re­quired to rise in it had much more to do with ruth­less­ness than wis­dom. Lenin’s core of Bol­she­viks, and the so­cial­ists like Trot­sky who joined them, were many of them highly ed­u­cated peo­ple, lit­er­ate in mul­ti­ple Eu­ro­pean lan­guages, learned in the scholas­tic tra­di­tions of Marx­ism; and they pre­served these at­trib­utes even as they mur­dered and lied and tor­tured and ter­ror­ized. They were so­cial sci­en­tists who thought prin­ci­ple re­quired them to be­have like gang­sters. But their suc­ces­sors – the vy­d­vizhentsy who re­filled the Cen­tral Com­mit­tee in the thir­ties – were not the most self­less peo­ple in So­viet so­ci­ety, or the most prin­ci­pled, or the most scrupu­lous. They were the most am­bi­tious, the most dom­i­neer­ing, the most ma­nip­u­la­tive, the most greedy, the most syco­phan­tic: peo­ple whose ad­her­ence to Bol­she­vik ideas was in­sep­a­ra­ble from the power that came with them. Grad­u­ally their loy­alty to the ideas be­came more and more in­stru­men­tal, more and more a mat­ter of what the ideas would let them grip in their two hands…

Stalin had been a gang­ster who re­ally be­lieved he was a so­cial sci­en­tist. Khr­uschev was a gang­ster who hoped he was a so­cial sci­en­tist. But the mo­ment was draw­ing ir­re­sistibly closer when the ide­al­ism would rot away by one more de­gree, and the So­viet Union would be gov­erned by gang­sters who were only pre­tend­ing to be so­cial sci­en­tists.

And in the end it all failed mis­er­ably:

The So­viet econ­omy did not move on from coal and steel and ce­ment to plas­tics and mi­cro­elec­tron­ics and soft­ware de­sign, ex­cept in a very few mil­i­tary ap­pli­ca­tions. It con­tin­ued to com­pete with what cap­i­tal­ism had been doing in the 1930s, not with what it was doing now. It con­tin­ued to suck re­sources and human labour in vast quan­ti­ties into a heavy-​industrial sec­tor which had once been in­tended to exist as a spring­board for some­thing else, but which by now had be­come its own jus­ti­fi­ca­tion. So­viet in­dus­try in its last decades ex­isted be­cause it ex­isted, an em­pire of in­er­tia ex­pand­ing ever more slowly, yet at­tain­ing the wretched dis­tinc­tion of ab­sorb­ing more of the total ef­fort of the econ­omy that hosted it than heavy in­dus­try has ever done any­where else in human his­tory, be­fore or since. Every year it pro­duced goods that less and less cor­re­sponded to human needs, and what­ever it once started pro­duc­ing, it tended to go on pro­duc­ing ad in­fini­tum, since it pos­sessed no ef­fec­tive stop sig­nals ex­cept ruth­less com­mands from above, and the peo­ple at the top no longer did ruth­less, in the eco­nomic sphere. The con­trol sys­tem for in­dus­try grew more and more er­ratic, the in­for­ma­tion flow­ing back to the plan­ners grew more and more cor­rupt. And the ac­tiv­ity of in­dus­try, all that human time and ma­chine time it used up, added less and less value to the raw ma­te­ri­als it sucked in. Maybe no value. Maybe less than none. One econ­o­mist has ar­gued that, by the end, it was ac­tively de­stroy­ing value; it had be­come a sys­tem for spoil­ing per­fectly good ma­te­ri­als by turn­ing them into ob­jects no one wanted.

I don’t know if this para­graph was in­ten­tion­ally writ­ten to con­trast with the para­graph at the top, the one about the zom­bie dance of cap­i­tal­ism. But it is cer­tainly in­struc­tive to make such a con­trast. The So­vi­ets had orig­i­nally been in­spired by this fear of eco­nom­ics going out of con­trol, aban­don­ing the human be­ings whose lives it was sup­posed to im­prove. In cap­i­tal­ist coun­tries, peo­ple ex­isted for the sake of the econ­omy, but under So­viet com­mu­nism, the econ­omy was going to exist only for the sake of the peo­ple.

(ac­ci­den­tal Russ­ian re­ver­sal: the best kind of Russ­ian re­ver­sal!)

And in­stead, they ended up tak­ing “peo­ple ex­ist­ing for the sake of the econ­omy” to en­tirely new and tragic ex­tremes, peo­ple being sent to the gu­lags or killed be­cause they didn’t meet the tar­gets for some prod­uct no­body wanted that was listed on a Five-​Year Plan. Spoil­ing good raw ma­te­ri­als for the sake of being able to tell Party bosses and the world “Look at us! We are doing In­dus­try!” Moloch had done some weird judo move on the So­vi­ets’ at­tempt to de­stroy him, and he had ended up stronger than ever.

The book’s great­est flaw is that it never did get into the de­tails of the math – or even more than a few-​sentence sum­mary of the math – and so I was left con­fused as to whether any­thing else had been pos­si­ble, whether Kan­torovich and Glushkov re­ally could have saved the vi­sion of pros­per­ity if they’d been al­lowed to do so. Nev­er­the­less, the So­vi­ets earned my sym­pa­thy and re­spect in a way Marx so far has not, merely by ac­knowl­edg­ing that the prob­lem ex­isted and through the ex­is­tence of a few good peo­ple who tried their best to solve it.

Med­i­ta­tions On MolochHomeThe God­dess of Every­thing Else
book re­vieweco­nom­icshis­torypol­i­ticsso­cial­ism